Often
we see popular protests against firm initiatives. Recently the Standing Rock
Sioux tribe and environmentalists organized protests against the planned Dakota
Access Pipeline, which was scheduled to run through sacred grounds and across a
river. The project has been suspended not because of protests, but because the
Army Corps of Engineers blocked the measure needed for it to be legal. Could the
construction backers have understood that the pipeline routing would lead to
protests? In retrospect it seems obvious that an oil pipe through sacred land
would be seen as a rough equivalent to an oil pipe through a church, and would
lead to some anger. But the more general question is, can firms learn to avoid
provoking activists?
It
turns out there is research showing that such learning happens, at least for
firms that are experienced with protests. An article in Administrative Science Quarterly by Lori Yue, Huggy Rao, and Paul Ingram studied the combination of
two events: protests against Wal-Mart Inc. store development proposals and
subsequent Target Corporation filing of store development proposals. This
sounds complicated, but it is a really simple sequence. Walmart needs to file a
proposal and have it approved in order to open a store (stores are big
projects). After a proposal is filed, there can be protests against it (many
dislike the idea of a nearby Walmart store), and Walmart can then decide
whether to stop planning for the store. Walmart is known to file many
proposals, and has a pattern of probing for places that are “protest-safe” by
the seeing whether there is a protest or not.
But
in our sequence, the next step is to see what Target does if there is a protest
after Walmart’s filing. Here it gets interesting. For Target, it could be a
simple rule to just avoid places with protests. In fact, they found that Target
does avoid places with protests, but it was also learning in smarter ways.
First, because Target knows that labor unions are uniformly unhappy with large
low-price (and low-wage) department stores, it pays less attention to union-organized
protests than to protests from other local groups. Second, it distinguished
between protests that specifically paint Walmart as evil, versus those that are
against any large store. Target is likely to enter when protests are specifically
against Walmart, but to avoid places with protests against big stores. So,
Target learns as much as possible from each protest.
And
Target is even more sophisticated than what I just wrote. These learning patterns
are what Target uses for locations that they are not familiar with, so they
need to use protests to learn instead of relying on own local knowledge. If
Target already has knowledge about a location, it ignores the protest and goes
ahead with its own plans based on the commercial promise and its own assessment
of risk.
Clearly,
a corporation needs to be pretty unpopular (and to have unpopular peers) to
become this good at learning from protests. And equally clearly, protests are
not just temporary solutions, they are also signals that firms pay attention to
and learn from. Protests have a deterrence effect, just as proposals have a
probing goal.