It is well known that firms ask for favors from the state
and often get them, with examples ranging from all the secretive lobbying in
the U.S. to the land use permits that politically connected firms seem to get
more often in many developing nations. But what do the firms give in return? In
democracies, the answer is easy: money. Donations to help re-elections are
channeled to politicians’ election campaigns from firms and their owners through
Political Action Committees in the U.S., ensuring that the politicians remain
grateful and compliant. Money does not work as well to secure the favors of state
officials who are not elected, however, unless they are corrupt, so the question
is what can firms do when seeking favors from unelected officials?
A recent article in Administrative Science Quarterly by Danqing Wang and Xiaowei Rose Luo explores this question using data on Chinese
firms during the market reform in the 10 years starting in 2001. They take
advantage of the fact that provincial government officials and party officials
have different goals, as do officials near retirement and younger officials
with much of their career ahead of them, to show that there is a very close
relation between the goals of important state officials and a very
consequential firm action: diversification through the acquisition of failed
firms. This was a period in which many state-owned firms that had enjoyed
significant state support before the reform failed and laid off their workers,
creating the potential for social unrest. Other independent firms could help
this unemployment problem (albeit unprofitably) by acquiring the failed firms
and continuing operations. Whether they helped or not was closely tied to the
careers of state officials.
The key insight is that party officials and government
officials both care about social stability and economic growth, but party
officials care especially about social stability, while government officials care
especially about economic growth. Taking this reasoning one step further,
government officials are generally more interested in economic growth, but when
provincial governors are close to retirement they become interested in social
stability too (it turns out to be good for their post-retirement careers).
Firms react to this in responding to calls for help for the failing firms. Having
a provincial governor near retirement makes them more likely to diversify in
response to layoffs by local firms, but having a provincial governor not close
to retirement has no effect. A party official near retirement has no effect
because party officials always care about social stability, so retirement does
not increase pressure on the firm.
Wang and Luo went one step further in showing that political
pressure changed firms’ diversification. They looked at whether the provincial level
of civil unrest could explain the firms’ reactions, whether retirement alone
could explain it, or whether it was a combination of the two. It turned out to
be the combination: layoffs, retirement, and civil unrest together made firms
help the governor by diversifying to absorb the laid-off workers.
So we know that firms are politically sensitive and can do
useful things like reducing unemployment. That’s often a good thing. The
problem lies somewhere else. The relationship between firms and the state is
one of give and take, so if you see firms giving they are usually taking
something else. If you can’t see what they are taking, you should probably
start worrying.